Tuesday, April 2, 2019
Inter Firm Relationships in the Silicon Fen
Inter steadfastly Relationships in the Silicon FenThe attention that thumpings consent received from polity makers and academics has considerably military issued in the last 20 age. Since door guards originative acetify on The Competitive Advantage of Nations (1990) recorded lots as one of the determinants of the international competitoryness of nations and regions, m whatever(prenominal) a(prenominal) scholars hold adopted and further genuine his approach. Porter bases his arguments on what he covers as the globalization paradox, particularing tabu that patronage the logical implications that the globalisation bring might have in dismissing the relevance of regional grammatical constituents, the close to free-enterprise(a) firms in world be set(p) in assemblyings geographical completelyy interchange shape in particular(prenominal) locations. That military position contri entirelyed to attr doinging attention to the humans of characteristics heret ofore to a topical anaesthetic place setting that could non be accessed by firms positioned elsewhere, and to a majusculeer extent, to the dogmatic personal effectuate that the parsimoniousness and the geographic law of propinquity could exert on the firms hawkishness. however influential, Porters ideas were non the precursor to discussing the matched outcomes originating from the geographic assimilation of firms (Martin and Sunley, 2003). The roots of dot speculation go back to the industrial districts identified by marshall (1890), who nominateed the prototypal detai lead description round the stinting and sociable systems make as a precede of the spacial c formerlyntrations of industrial activities. The Marshallian industrial districts were arrangements of small firms matching by commercial trading operations (buyers and sellers) and former(a) firms engaged in the said(prenominal) or correspondent activities, that dual-lane productive factors, such a s the agitate market, foot and tacit association (Becattini, 2004, p. 68). According to Marshals descriptions, a group of firms bring in one item sector within a well-defined, voiceless and comparatively small geographic atomic offspring 18a would experience juicyer levels of productiveness and humanity, so the winnings of a fertile environment for technical and organisational companionships. thus the topical anaesthetic characteristics would enable the emersion of an industrial atmosphere that would increase the firms dominance to acquire (especially tacit) knowledge, and ca-ca positive external economies accessible save to the firms rigid within the district (Asheim, 2003, p. 416). That perspective tried to evidence that firms geographically saturated could accesses confine positive exogenous benefits (exogenous to firms, alone endogenous to the district), which would be an substitute to the collection plate economies obtaind by a individual ( inco rporated) firm.Additionally, hobby round of the seminal ideas proposed by Marshall, it is affirmable to honor a epoch-making enactment of economicalalal geographers that in addition explored regional exploitation using the spatial economic agglomeration to put forward their ideas. whatever(prenominal) practice sessions of innovations emergent from that theoretical trend atomic issuing 18 regional innovation milieux (Crevoisier, 2004), neo-Marshallian nodes (Amin and Thrift, 1992) and learning regions (Asheim, 1995). More examples ass be establish in Markusen (1996, p. 297), in which a nonher three antithetical types of industrial districts ar expound harmonize to the firms configurations, infixed versus external orientations and governance structures a hub-and-spoke industrial district, which is arduous round one or more dominant firms a satellite platform, formed by a group of unconnected branches implant in external links and the sound out-anchored district, severe on one or more public-sector institutions. Despite the logical and robust assumptions found in legion(predicate) of those concepts, their fascinate and dispersion were non as productive as the more universal crew framework proposed by Porter. Martin and Sunley (2003) attributes the successful distribution of the Porter concepts to the truly general descriptions and de restrictionations that encompass a wide range of actors and umpteen diverse structures. by-line much of the concepts proposed by Porter, the description of payoffs conferred on gather firms associated with a general and structured analytical framework wound up the exploitation and dissemination of academic studies and subsidized the creation of supply-side war-riddenness policies directed at structuring and accompaniment the victimisation of lumps (Pitelis, 2010). That fact resulted in what Martin and Sunley (2003) describe as a polity panacea in the use of practice bundlings as a measuring stick ( round eons the unique) buttocks for promoting scrap, innovation and economic exploitation. Moreover, in the last 20 years an increase mo of empirical studies in disparate countries and sectors have been spy, which tendency to pick up and discuss the competitory outcomes originating from the concentration of firms and other actors in the said(prenominal) location, for example Brazil shoe manufacturing in the Sinos valley (Schmitz, 2000) Spain the textile and wearable industries in Catalonia (Porter, 1998) Taiwan electronic products at the Hsinchu Science Park (Chen, 2008) and the coupled States electronic electronic computer and information systems at the Silicon Valley (Saxenian, 1994).The large meaning(a) number of academic studies has resulted in a large number of comments aiming to describe and spend a penny an accepted practice bundling template (e.g., Enright, 1996 Swann and Prevezer, 1996, Rosenfeld, 1997 Porter, 1998) to support poli cy makers and academics has led to fierce debates and controversial perspectives. unconstipated though the concept of studs has been change magnitudely astray disseminated and apply by geographers, economists and policy makers, it has suffered from somewhat conceptual confusion. Porter defines a foregather as a geographic concentration of interconnected companies, specialised suppliers, swear out providers firms in related industries, and associated institutions (for example, universities, standards agencies and trade associations) in particular field that compete but also co-operate (1998, p. 197). However, Martin and Sunley (2003, p. 12) present consistent arguments that indicate the vagueness and superficiality of the concept proposed by Porter. According to their arguments, those characteristics make the concept of meet direction antithetic things to divergent researchers and policy makers, creating problems for its proper use in the advocate of academics and re gimens. Those super controversial aspects of the crowd theory have getd the unceasing military issue of refreshing concepts and descriptions for clusters.Proposing a definition aiming to fill some of the gaps and failures found in existent cluster theory, Pitelis (2010, p. 5) defines clusters as geographical agglomerations of firms in particular, related, and/or complementary, activities, with a geographical dimension, that exhibit horizontal and/or vertical intra- and/or inter-sectoral linkages, which operate in the context of a facilitatory socio-institutional setting, and which co-operate and compete (co-opete) in inter-national markets. That definition tries offer to a more delimited approach that incorporates quartet study elements geographical agglomeration, linkages, social- with child(p)1and co-opetition (competition and cooperation). The use of those four elements in a single definition offers the gap to cover the cluster characteristics using delimited criteria to name and break up unquestionable clusters from less abstruse geographical agglomerations of firms and institutions.Although it is assertable to observe some level of ambiguity encompassing the clusters theory, the man of links interconnecting topical anaesthetic actors complemented by geographical dimensions constitute some of the main putting green points use to delineate academics and policy makers with interesting by the hawkish outcomes originating from clusters. Those characteristics have much been employ as the fiting point to recognise the economic kinetics of forgather firms, putting emphasis on the levels of innovation and productivity emerging from the concentration of different actors in the analogous bea.Suggesting narrowal characteristics to the heading of competitive advantages obtained by firms inner clusters, Ketels (2004) considers that the positive economic effects originated from the geographical concentration bequeath however regard co me forward if four captious characteristics be overlap among firms and institutionsProximity they must be geographically close to pass on the emergence of knowledge spillovers and to shargon the aforesaid(prenominal) green re point of referencesLinkages the necessity of similarities in their activities leading(p) to the establishment of connections and synergiesInteractions the social interactions developed among firms, clients, suppliers, research institutes, and so on, is what forms the social capital that becomes accomplishable firms to achieve differentiated competitive surgerysCritical mess it is grave to have a earthshaking number of firms and institutions in score to create meaningful tinges on exercise of the topical anaesthetic actors.Those characteristics exposit by Ketels whitethorn be used to guide the identification and distinction surrounded by developed clusters (Pitelis, 2010) from incipient clusters (Schmitz, 1999) in society to dismiss some ludic rous interpretations associated with the clusters kinetics. Considering that the nominal head of geographic concentration of firms in the similar attention is strikingly common around the world (Porter, 1990, p.120), it is necessary the use of specific benchmarks to depict and demote different groups of firms geographically concentrated check to their specific characteristics (Gordon and McCann, 2000 Isbasoiu, 2006).Describing how the conception of topical anaesthetic anaesthetic anesthetic capabilities2create differentiated conditions for companies within real clusters, Menzel and Fornahl (2010) argue that clusters argon funda kindly formed from path dependencies (Martin and Sunley, 2006), transaction be economies (McCann and Sheppard, 2003) and small cognitive distances originating from spatial proximity (Maskell, 2001). Thus, that set of factors are pass judgment to create a specific regional dynamics with influence on the firms economic exercise. taking into consi derateness the different academic degrees of a cluster life story hertz, and the mis taking into custodys related to the claims associated with the clusters and conflict, Schmitz points out that A group of small producers making the equal or similar things in close vicinity to each other constitutes a cluster, but such concentration in itself brings few benefits (1999, p. 4), emphasizing that the mere nominal head of firms in a delimited area does not represent a stemma of place creation able to improve in a significant counsel the topical anaesthetic economic feat. undermentioned the arguments above, the differences between regional clusters and plain agglomerations (groups of firms) lie mainly on the interconnected nature and spatial proximity. Thus, clusters are characterized by wicked collaborative intercommunicates and concentrations of collaboration and competition (co-opetitition) (Pitelis, 2010), conditions which offer significant opportunities and stimulate th e emergence of regional competitive advantages (Steinle and Schiele, 2002). Complementarily, another particular characteristic as certain(prenominal)ed within clusters is the diversity of actors. According to Porter (1990, 1998, 2000), an industrial cluster includes suppliers, consumers, related industries, politicss, and supporting institutions such as universities. This way, the cosmos of a regional network formed by a significant group of interconnected topical anaesthetic anesthetic actors is one of the small factors to understand the differentiated competitive performance of firms within clusters (Steinle and Schiele, 2002). Illustrating that argument, Saxenian (1994) find that Hewlett Packard and other firms at the Silicon Valley had their performance improved by the developing long-term partnerships with suppliers located geographically close. Moreover, found on that observation, Saxenian concluded that, especially in spicy-tech industries, the somatogenic proximity represents a facilitator to the establishment of efficient collaborative arrangements required to create and lot heterogeneous products and services.1.2 Evolutionary Stages of Industrial thumpsDespite the vast cluster literature, the number of academic works discussing the evolutionary patterns of clusters over eon is not so extensive. Some examples can be found in Pouder and John (1996), Klepper (2001, 2007), Wolter (2003) and Andersson et al., (2004), and despite the diverging perspectives, it is accepted that clusters follow a kind of life steering wheel comprised by different phases that significantly differ in their characteristics and influence on firms performance. Regarding the cluster dynamics, Pouder and John (1996) argue that comparative analysis between flock and non-agglomerate firms during the industriousness life make pass reveal that firms within clusters outperform those geographically sprinkle at the sign spirit levelcoachs of development, and have a wor se performance at its end. That fact suggests that the cluster life cycle is not fair a local representation of the effort escape, but is a result from local peculiarities. The comparative analysis developed by Saxenian (1994) between the computer persistence in Boston and Silicon Valley illustrates how different clusters belong to the uniform industry are very believably to follow different trajectories (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010).Proposing a different perspective, Klepper (2001, 2007) suggests a influence to demonstrate how the clusters life cycle is mulish by some the industry patterns. Klepper analyzed the automobile, tire and idiot box industries and ascertained that at the beginning of the industry life cycle it was not possible to observe clear geographic concentrations of firms, with most of the firms spatially disperse. He observed that in those industries clusters sourceed to emerge and develop according to the industry growth rates. Klepper argues that the local characteristics originating from the spacial proximity (e.g., intensive spin-off process) give the stimulation for the geographic agglomeration of the whole industry, not altogether for specific groups. At the time the industry growth rate reduces, the attractiveness to anticipate agglomerated go away also decrease and the industry will become dispersed again. That copy proposed by Klepper represents a Technology-Product- Industry (TIP) life cycle. The logic behind this model is on the impact that the evolution of products and innovations has on the size, number, and location of firms. Wolter (2003) criticizes the model proposed by Klepper literary argument that the growth rate cannot explicate the agglomeration process in all industries on equal basis. Moreover, Wolter disagrees with the determinist perspective proposed by the TIP model, once it neglects that come along industries can be reinvented by radical or additive innovations of tonic products and process.Analyzing the economic performance of firms within clusters Pouder and John (1996) attribute to the existence of mental models and biased cognitive focus the characteristics responsible for shape the social movement with and finished the clusters life cycle. Following that perspective, at initial stages the cluster dynamics creates an mod environment that exerts positive impacts on the firms performance. However, overtime that initial condition is wear away by strong institutional pressures that create a self-colored macroculture that acts inhibiting the groundbreaking capacity of the firms within the cluster. As in the model presented by Klepper (2001, 2007), that trajectory proposed by Pouder and John whitethorn also be criticized by the determinism that ignores the possibility of readjustments or reconfigurations in order to avoid lock-ins and other minus effects.Considering the arguments proposed by Menzel and Fornahl (2010, p. 8) that very few clusters follow a rigid life cycl e from emergence to growth and decline, it is expected that clusters evolve overtime according to the local dynamics created by economic and social interactions among firms and institutions. That dynamics whitethorn be influenced, but not strictly placed by industry patterns (Wolter, 2003). Following a generic and stylized trajectory, within successful clusters the local network formed by inter-firm connections will tend to be intensify overtime, with an change magnitude number of formal and informal interactions between the long-established companies and newborn the ones attracted to the cluster. Even though it is more conceivable to assume that the decisions adopted by firms and institutions are shaped by specific circumstances, a generic trajectory can be described following the stages illustrated in Figure 1.Figure 1 The cluster life cycleCUsersLucasAppDataLocalMicrosoftWindowsTemporary Internet FilesContent.WordSem ttulo.jpg author Andersson et al. (2004, p. 43)Agglomerat ion It is possible to observe the existence of a number of companies and other actors (e.g. banks, government agencies, universities, accountants, and lawyers offices) in a specific region working around the same or interrelated activities.Emerging cluster Forming the embryo to the cluster some actors start to cooperation around some core activities, and start to realize the existence of common linkages.Developing cluster The linkages are intensified by the emergence and loss leader of new actors to the region, resulting in the creation of more interaction. In this context the development of inter-firm-cooperation becomes more evident through the development of union efforts.The advance cluster This stage is configured by the presence of a certain critical mass of factors that consistently influence the competitive performance of the firms interior the cluster. The internal dynamics is characterized by the presence of an institutional environment, strong linkages, complementarit ies and the emergence of new firms through startups, joint ventures and spin-offs.Transformation Indeed the process of unremitting environmental change in markets, technologies, regulations and other process, to be successful a cluster have to put in and adapt to these new conditions, other way stagnancy and decay whitethorn affect the cluster dynamics. That process of change/adaptation may happen through the emergence of one or some(prenominal) interconnected clusters with focus in other activities, or by new configuration in basis of networks of firms and institutions.The presence of economic benefits for agglomerated firms described by authors like Schmitz and Nadvi (1999), Ketels (2004), Isbasoiu (2006) and Pitelis and Pseiridis (2006) are closely related to the stage of development that a cluster is experiencing. For example, an emerging cluster is not very a cluster, since the small number of firms is not expected to present a high level of linkages and do not form a cri tical mass. Moreover, the absence seizure of strong interdependencies such as jab mobility, spin-off, socioeconomic networks and intense transfer of good and services prevent the emergence of local capabilities. Thus, same considering that this stage constitutes the embryo that determines the future cluster orientation, at this point the firms are not expected to be strongly influenced by a complex local dynamics.Observing that fact, Menzel and Fornahl (2010) present a skeptical position regarding the effectuality of any competitiveness policy intended to stimulate the development of clusters at initial stages (agglomeration and emerging), since the existence of horizontal and vertical links among firms concentrated in the same region constitutes a very common fact around the world. Thus, it is close impossible to distinguish agglomerations with real potential to become a cluster from less complex structures. Consequently, emerging clusters are almost ever only described ex-post .After the initial stages of the clusters life cycle it is expected the development and intensification of interdependencies between firms within cluster boundaries (Press, 2006). Indeed the development of those interdependencies, firms start to correspond more with each other, being observe the emergence of focussed designs in terms of technological models (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010), change labour market (Cooke et al., 2007), product systems (Pitelis, 2010) and inter-firm relationships (Blien and Maier, 2008). Moreover, developing clusters also attract a high number of start-ups that act touch the intensification of intra-cluster relationships. This way, that process of convergence and expansion of the number of firms within the cluster boundaries culminates in the development of self-reinforcing external economies that decrease the heterogeneity among firms at the same time that creates benefits like minutes cost economies and the privileged access to local knowledge.As clus ters feed the stage of maturity, the standards and configurations originating from past decisions become consolidate and it is observed a reduction in the growth rate of firms attracted to the cluster (Klepper, 2007). At this point the cluster trajectory may take two different directions. play along unchanged, and suffer with a homogenization process that creates bias economic activities and thence prevent firms to adapt to external shocks (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010). That situation traps firms in preliminary successful development path and lead to the geographic dispersion of the local actors and to the constipation of the interdependencies and capabilities. The other possible trajectory is observed in clusters that reach the stage of maturity and successfully sustain the local dynamics by a continuous process of reconfiguration and adaptation to the external shocks (Wolter, 2003).1.2 Clusters and Economic transactionThe extant theory offers a wide range of explanations to jus tify the economic and competitive benefits experienced by firms located within clusters. Krugman (1991) stress the existence of increasing returns originating from the concentration of firms in the same area, arguing that the geographic proximity puts together the main parts related to firms activities (e.g., labours, firms, suppliers and costumers) resulting in transaction costs economies. Following other perspective, Schmitz and Nadvi (1999) argue that unintentional external economies are not comfortable to explain the competitiveness of firms located within clusters, attributing to the existence of deliberate joint actions (e.g., sharing equipments, associations, strategic alliances and producers improving components) a critical source of the competitive advantages. Pitelis and Pseiridis (2006) explain the levels of competitiveness and productivity associated with clustered firms considering the existence of specialized kind-hearted resources, infrastructure and befits associ ated with unit costs economies complemented by the presence of an institutional atmosphere. Stressing a different point of view, Bahlmann and Huysman (2008) adopts the knowledge- found view of clusters to emphasize the relevance of knowledge spillovers among the firms to explain the advantages originated from the agglomeration process. Dupuy and Torre (2006) explains the existence of cluster in terms of the advantages originating from trust relationships that increase assumption and reduce risk and uncertainty about the intra-cluster operations taking place among the firms. Moreover, Zyglidopoulos et al. (2003), describe the positive effects that the reputation of a cluster may exert on the internalization process of small and little enterprises through the alleviation of strategic constraints associated with factors like qualified work force, financial support and reduction of the firms legitimation expenses.Despite that wide range of arguments, the most conventional perspectiv e found in the cluster literature has explained the competitive advantages of clusters in terms of productivity and innovation (Pitelis, 1998 Porter, 1998), suggesting that the special characteristics originated from the economic and geographic proximity have significant impact on those two factors. Supplementary, Enright (1998) considers that the characteristics present inside the clusters local environment result in pressures, incentives and capabilities that increase the firms competitiveness relatively to dispersed competitors, explaining the clustering process in terms of geographically circumscribe characteristics.Moreover, Solvell et al. (2003) suggests that the competitive advantages emerging from regional clusters may be classified as silent and dynamics. According to this perspective, while the agglomeration process triggered and sustained intensively or simply by factors like cancel resources, low cost labors and government subsidies offers a vulnerable (easy to be co pied, substituted or simple eroded by environmental changes) competitive position, clusters base on dynamics characteristics like multi-sectorial externalities, advantages of scale and orbital cavity and specific knowledge spillovers are more dynamics and competitive. Extending the arguments presented by Solvell and his colleagues, Andersson et al. (2004) considers that the sustainability of electro placid and dynamic competitive advantages is not strictly determined, arguing that static factors are the main responsible for the emergence of clusters, while the dynamics factors are only developed along the different stages of the cluster life cycle.Complementing the understanding about the influence of the cluster dynamics on the firms economic performance some authors like Porter (2001) Garnsey and Heffernan (2007) Karlsson (2008) and Mason (2008) describe the existence of a self-reinforcing process originating from the agglomeration externalities that contribute to create a regi onal virtuous-circle of increasing productivity, competitiveness and value creation. Following that argument, the economic and geographic proximity will stimulate firms to innovate more indeed benefits originating from local capabilities, which will stimulate even more the agglomeration process through the intensification of inter-firm relationships and the attraction of other firms from outside the cluster, which in turn will strength the local capabilities (Blandy, 2003, p. 101). Thus, the dynamics of clusters is expected to be self-reinforced by agglomeration benefits with significant influence on the firms performance.Putting together the arguments associated with the economic impacts experienced by clustered firms indeed the existence of local factors, it is possible to rate and describe the following positive location-specific externalitiesCost savings indeed the geographic proximity with specialized suppliers, labours and distributorsKnowledge-spillovers (intentional and uni ntentional), since firms inside clusters can benefit from the knowledge dissemination process that may take place especially through inter-firm cooperation, specific linkages and labour mobilityDeliberate joint actions facilitated by the engagement in alliances and partnerships to achieve strategic objectivesTrust relationships, that through the geographic and economic proximity downplay the uncertainty associated with commercial operations, resulting in transactions costs economiesPressures for high performance, stimulated by the proximity with competitorsSpecific Infrastructure and public goods that are point to attend the cluster demands, like roads, ports, laboratories and telecommunication networksComplementarities, associated with firms in different activities but sharing common factors like raw material, clients and technologies that may produce the cluster efficiency as whole.Discussing the role of regional clusters in shaping competitive patterns, Tallman et al. (2004) p roposes a distinction between the types of competitive advantages emerging from clustered firms based on traded interdependencies and based on untraded interdependencies. The concept of traded interdependencies is related to the existence of inter-firm transactions inside the cluster, and is observed in formal exchange operations that may take place in form of alliances, commercial operations and acquisitions. On the other hand, untraded interdependencies are related to less tangible effects, and are based on shared knowledge for which no market mechanism exists with no formal exchange of value for value (Tallman et al. 2004, p. 261). To illustrate the mechanisms by which the untraded interdependencies take place, it is possible to mention unintentional external economies associated with tacit knowledge shared through mechanisms like labor mobility.Those different types of interdependencies, especially untraded, present at the cluster level, represent a source of competitive advant age that is likely to be causal ambiguous (for firms inside and outside the cluster) and high complex in terms of their origins, what consequently constitutes attributes difficult to be replicated by competitors. However, the presence of untraded effects, especially unintentional knowledge spillovers, is viewed Enright (1998) as a limiting factor for firms within clusters, since the establishment of an efficient information flow may limit the firms capacity to obtain monopoly profits from the development of innovations.Complementing the negative effects originating from the clusters dynamics, some authors also describe agglomeration diseconomies that have a negative impact firms located within clusters. For example, congestion effects (Arthur, 1990), institutional sclerosis (Pouder and John, 1996 Pitelis, 2010), rigidities associated with labour mobility and natural resources (Krugman, 1989) and pollution (Fan and Scott, 2003). This way, the dynamics and performance of a cluster is determined by the interplay between positive and negative externalities observed during the different stages of development that a cluster is expected to pass overtime (Wolter, 2003)Limitations in the Cluster schemeNotwithstanding the advances in the cluster theory some questions gloss over remain insufficiently explored. One of the main limitations observed in the genuine state of the cluster literature is the lack of comparative perspectives to explain the advantages and disadvantages of clusters relatively to other alternative models of organization of economic activities. In his very wise approach, Pitelis (2010) suggests that any perspective trying to explain clusters in terms of arbitrary advantages is at the very best incomplete. In this context, Pitelis proposes the comparison of clusters vis--vis to markets and hierarchies in order to understand the reasons and conditions that lead firms to engage in intra-clusters relationships, market operations (outside the cluster) or integrate within the firms hierarchy. In fact it is not necessary a great effort to conclude that most of the cluster theory has been developed following a mono-institutional approach (e.g. Porter, 1990, 1998 Saxenian, 1994 Rosenfeld, 1998 Swann and Sennett, 1998 Schmitz and Nadvi, 1999), while some few exceptions concentrated on transactions costs (e.g. Fujita and Thisse, 1996 Iammarino and McCann, 2006 Takeda et al., 2008) and knowledge creation efficiency (e.g. Hendry et al., 2000 Tracey and Clark, 2003 Reinau, 2007 Kongmanila and Takahashi, 2009) have been skeletal on a comparative approaches between clusters and open-market operations. Assuming the arguments proposed by some scholars that clusters are engines of innovation (Davis, 2006, p. 32), the lack of comparative perspectives do not come the question why clusters are more efficient than markets or the hierarchy to improve the firms advance(a) capacity (Pitelis, 2010). Thus, despite the wide number of ramifications observed in the cluster theory such as innovative efficiency, productivity, social capital and social interactions, its explicative power remains almost constantly restrictedInter Firm Relationships in the Silicon FenInter Firm Relationships in the Silicon FenThe attention that clusters have received from policy makers and academics has substantially increased in the last 20 years. Since Porters seminal work on The Competitive Advantage of Nations (1990) presented clusters as one of the determinants of the international competitiveness of nations and regions, many scholars have adopted and further developed his approach. Porter bases his arguments on what he describes as the globalization paradox, pointing out that despite the logical implications that the globalisation process might have in dismissing the relevance of regional factors, the most competitive firms in world are located in groups geographically concentrated in specific locations. That perspective contributed to attra cting attention to the existence of characteristics tied to a local context that could not be accessed by firms positioned elsewhere, and more, to the positive effects that the concentration and the geographic proximity could exert on the firms competitiveness.However influential, Porters ideas were not the precursor to discussing the competitive outcomes originating from the geographic concentration of firms (Martin and Sunley, 2003). The roots of cluster theory go back to the industrial districts identified by Marshall (1890), who offered the first detailed description about the economic and social systems created as a result of the spacial concentrations of industrial activities. The Marshallian industrial districts were arrangements of small firms interconnected by commercial operations (buyers and sellers) and other firms engaged in the same or similar activities, that shared productive factors, such as the labour market, infrastructure and tacit knowledge (Becattini, 2004, p. 68). According to Marshals descriptions, a group of firms operating in one specific sector within a well-defined, concentrated and relatively small geographic area would experience high levels of productivity and innovation, indeed the emergence of a fertile environment for technical and organisational developments. Thus the local characteristics would enable the emergence of an industrial atmosphere that would increase the firms potential to acquire (especially tacit) knowledge, and create positive external economies accessible only to the firms located within the district (Asheim, 2003, p. 416). That perspective tried to evidence that firms geographically concentrated could accesses restricted positive exogenous benefits (exogenous to firms, but endogenous to the district), which would be an alternative to the scale economies achieved by a single (integrated) firm.Additionally, following some of the seminal ideas proposed by Marshall, it is possible to observe a significant numbe r of economic geographers that also explored regional development using the spatial economic agglomeration to support their ideas. Some examples of concepts emerging from that theoretical trend are regional innovation milieux (Crevoisier, 2004), neo-Marshallian nodes (Amin and Thrift, 1992) and learning regions (Asheim, 1995). More examples can be found in Markusen (1996, p. 297), in which another three different types of industrial districts are described according to the firms configurations, internal versus external orientations and governance structures a hub-and-spoke industrial district, which is concentrated around one or more dominant firms a satellite platform, formed by a group of unconnected branches embedded in external links and the state-anchored district, concentrated on one or more public-sector institutions. Despite the logical and robust assumptions found in many of those concepts, their influence and dissemination were not as successful as the more general cluster framework proposed by Porter. Martin and Sunley (2003) attributes the successful dissemination of the Porter concepts to the very general descriptions and delimitations that encompass a wide range of actors and many different structures.Following much of the concepts proposed by Porter, the description of advantages conferred on clustered firms associated with a general and structured analytical framework stimulated the development and dissemination of academic studies and subsidized the creation of supply-side competitiveness policies directed at structuring and supporting the development of clusters (Pitelis, 2010). That fact resulted in what Martin and Sunley (2003) describe as a policy panacea in the use of clusters as a standard (sometimes the unique) target for promoting competitiveness, innovation and economic growth. Moreover, in the last 20 years an increasing number of empirical studies in different countries and sectors have been observed, which aim to identify and discu ss the competitive outcomes originating from the concentration of firms and other actors in the same location, for example Brazil shoe manufacturing in the Sinos Valley (Schmitz, 2000) Spain the textile and clothing industries in Catalonia (Porter, 1998) Taiwan electronic products at the Hsinchu Science Park (Chen, 2008) and the United States computer and information systems at the Silicon Valley (Saxenian, 1994).The large significant number of academic studies has resulted in a large number of definitions aiming to describe and establish an accepted cluster template (e.g., Enright, 1996 Swann and Prevezer, 1996, Rosenfeld, 1997 Porter, 1998) to support policy makers and academics has led to intense debates and controversial perspectives. Even though the concept of clusters has been increasingly widely disseminated and used by geographers, economists and policy makers, it has suffered from some conceptual confusion. Porter defines a cluster as a geographic concentration of inter connected companies, specialized suppliers, service providers firms in related industries, and associated institutions (for example, universities, standards agencies and trade associations) in particular fields that compete but also co-operate (1998, p. 197). However, Martin and Sunley (2003, p. 12) present consistent arguments that indicate the vagueness and superficiality of the concept proposed by Porter. According to their arguments, those characteristics make the concept of cluster means different things to different researchers and policy makers, creating problems for its proper use in the guidance of academics and governments. Those highly controversial aspects of the cluster theory have stimulated the continuous emergence of new concepts and definitions for clusters.Proposing a definition aiming to fill some of the gaps and failures found in extant cluster theory, Pitelis (2010, p. 5) defines clusters as geographical agglomerations of firms in particular, related, and/or com plementary, activities, with a geographical dimension, that exhibit horizontal and/or vertical intra- and/or inter-sectoral linkages, which operate in the context of a facilitatory socio-institutional setting, and which co-operate and compete (co-opete) in inter-national markets. That definition tries offer to a more delimited approach that incorporates four major elements geographical agglomeration, linkages, social-capital1and co-opetition (competition and cooperation). The use of those four elements in a single definition offers the possibility to cover the cluster characteristics using delimited criteria to identify and distinguish developed clusters from less complex geographical agglomerations of firms and institutions.Although it is possible to observe some level of ambiguity encompassing the clusters theory, the existence of links interconnecting local actors complemented by geographical dimensions constitute some of the main common points used to guide academics and policy makers with interesting by the competitive outcomes originating from clusters. Those characteristics have frequently been used as the starting point to understand the economic dynamics of clustered firms, putting emphasis on the levels of innovation and productivity emerging from the concentration of different actors in the same area.Suggesting conditional characteristics to the presence of competitive advantages obtained by firms inside clusters, Ketels (2004) considers that the positive economic effects originated from the geographical concentration will only take place if four critical characteristics are shared among firms and institutionsProximity they must be geographically close to allow the emergence of knowledge spillovers and to share the same common resourcesLinkages the necessity of similarities in their activities leading to the establishment of connections and synergiesInteractions the social interactions developed among firms, clients, suppliers, research institutes, and so on, is what forms the social capital that becomes possible firms to achieve differentiated competitive performancesCritical mass it is important to have a significant number of firms and institutions in order to create meaningful impacts on performance of the local actors.Those characteristics described by Ketels may be used to guide the identification and distinction between developed clusters (Pitelis, 2010) from incipient clusters (Schmitz, 1999) in order to dismiss some incorrect interpretations associated with the clusters dynamics. Considering that the presence of geographic concentration of firms in the same industry is strikingly common around the world (Porter, 1990, p.120), it is necessary the use of specific benchmarks to distinguish and classify different groups of firms geographically concentrated according to their specific characteristics (Gordon and McCann, 2000 Isbasoiu, 2006).Describing how the existence of local capabilities2create differentiated conditions for companies within real clusters, Menzel and Fornahl (2010) argue that clusters are essentially formed from path dependencies (Martin and Sunley, 2006), transaction costs economies (McCann and Sheppard, 2003) and small cognitive distances originating from spatial proximity (Maskell, 2001). Thus, that set of factors are expected to create a specific regional dynamics with influence on the firms economic performance. Taking into consideration the different stages of a cluster life cycle, and the misunderstandings related to the claims associated with the clusters and competitiveness, Schmitz points out that A group of small producers making the same or similar things in close vicinity to each other constitutes a cluster, but such concentration in itself brings few benefits (1999, p. 4), emphasizing that the mere presence of firms in a delimited area does not represent a source of value creation able to improve in a significant way the local economic performance.Following the argume nts above, the differences between regional clusters and simple agglomerations (groups of firms) lie mainly on the interconnected nature and spatial proximity. Thus, clusters are characterized by intense collaborative networks and concentrations of collaboration and competition (co-opetitition) (Pitelis, 2010), conditions which offer significant opportunities and stimulate the emergence of regional competitive advantages (Steinle and Schiele, 2002). Complementarily, another critical characteristic observed within clusters is the diversity of actors. According to Porter (1990, 1998, 2000), an industrial cluster includes suppliers, consumers, related industries, governments, and supporting institutions such as universities. This way, the existence of a regional network formed by a significant group of interconnected local actors is one of the critical factors to understand the differentiated competitive performance of firms within clusters (Steinle and Schiele, 2002). Illustrating tha t argument, Saxenian (1994) observed that Hewlett Packard and other firms at the Silicon Valley had their performance improved by the development long-term partnerships with suppliers located geographically close. Moreover, based on that observation, Saxenian concluded that, especially in high-tech industries, the physical proximity represents a facilitator to the establishment of efficient collaborative arrangements required to create and manage complex products and services.1.2 Evolutionary Stages of Industrial ClustersDespite the vast cluster literature, the number of academic works discussing the evolutionary patterns of clusters overtime is not so extensive. Some examples can be found in Pouder and John (1996), Klepper (2001, 2007), Wolter (2003) and Andersson et al., (2004), and despite the divergent perspectives, it is accepted that clusters follow a kind of life cycle comprised by different phases that significantly differ in their characteristics and influence on firms perf ormance. Regarding the cluster dynamics, Pouder and John (1996) argue that comparative analysis between clustered and non-clustered firms during the industry life cycle reveal that firms within clusters outperform those geographically dispersed at the initial stages of development, and have a worse performance at its end. That fact suggests that the cluster life cycle is not just a local representation of the industry trajectory, but is a result from local peculiarities. The comparative analysis developed by Saxenian (1994) between the computer industry in Boston and Silicon Valley illustrates how different clusters belonging to the same industry are very likely to follow different trajectories (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010).Proposing a different perspective, Klepper (2001, 2007) suggests a model to demonstrate how the clusters life cycle is determined by some the industry patterns. Klepper analyzed the automobile, tire and television industries and observed that at the beginning of the industry life cycle it was not possible to observe clear geographic concentrations of firms, with most of the firms spatially dispersed. He observed that in those industries clusters started to emerge and develop according to the industry growth rates. Klepper argues that the local characteristics originating from the spacial proximity (e.g., intensive spin-off process) give the stimulus for the geographic agglomeration of the whole industry, not only for specific groups. At the time the industry growth rate reduces, the attractiveness to remain agglomerated will also decrease and the industry will become dispersed again. That model proposed by Klepper represents a Technology-Product- Industry (TIP) life cycle. The logic behind this model is on the impact that the evolution of products and innovations has on the size, number, and location of firms. Wolter (2003) criticizes the model proposed by Klepper arguing that the growth rate cannot explain the agglomeration process in all ind ustries on equal basis. Moreover, Wolter disagrees with the determinist perspective proposed by the TIP model, once it neglects that mature industries can be reinvented by radical or incremental innovations of new products and process.Analyzing the economic performance of firms within clusters Pouder and John (1996) attribute to the existence of mental models and biased cognitive focus the characteristics responsible for shaping the movement through the clusters life cycle. Following that perspective, at initial stages the cluster dynamics creates an innovative environment that exerts positive impacts on the firms performance. However, overtime that initial condition is eroded by strong institutional pressures that create a homogeneous macroculture that acts inhibiting the innovative capacity of the firms within the cluster. As in the model presented by Klepper (2001, 2007), that trajectory proposed by Pouder and John may also be criticized by the determinism that ignores the possib ility of adaptations or reconfigurations in order to avoid lock-ins and other negative effects.Considering the arguments proposed by Menzel and Fornahl (2010, p. 8) that very few clusters follow a rigid life cycle from emergence to growth and decline, it is expected that clusters evolve overtime according to the local dynamics created by economic and social interactions among firms and institutions. That dynamics may be influenced, but not strictly determined by industry patterns (Wolter, 2003). Following a generic and stylized trajectory, within successful clusters the local network formed by inter-firm connections will tend to be intensified overtime, with an increasing number of formal and informal interactions between the long-established companies and new the ones attracted to the cluster. Even though it is more conceivable to assume that the decisions adopted by firms and institutions are shaped by specific circumstances, a generic trajectory can be described following the sta ges illustrated in Figure 1.Figure 1 The cluster life cycleCUsersLucasAppDataLocalMicrosoftWindowsTemporary Internet FilesContent.WordSem ttulo.jpg Source Andersson et al. (2004, p. 43)Agglomeration It is possible to observe the existence of a number of companies and other actors (e.g. banks, government agencies, universities, accountants, and lawyers offices) in a specific region working around the same or interrelated activities.Emerging cluster Forming the embryo to the cluster some actors start to cooperation around some core activities, and start to realize the existence of common linkages.Developing cluster The linkages are intensified by the emergence and attraction of new actors to the region, resulting in the creation of more interaction. In this context the development of inter-firm-cooperation becomes more evident through the development of joint efforts.The Mature cluster This stage is configured by the presence of a certain critical mass of factors that consistently inf luence the competitive performance of the firms inside the cluster. The internal dynamics is characterized by the presence of an institutional environment, strong linkages, complementarities and the emergence of new firms through startups, joint ventures and spin-offs.Transformation Indeed the process of continuous environmental change in markets, technologies, regulations and other process, to be successful a cluster have to innovate and adapt to these new conditions, other way stagnation and decay may affect the cluster dynamics. That process of change/adaptation may happen through the emergence of one or several interconnected clusters with focus in other activities, or by new configuration in terms of networks of firms and institutions.The presence of economic benefits for clustered firms described by authors like Schmitz and Nadvi (1999), Ketels (2004), Isbasoiu (2006) and Pitelis and Pseiridis (2006) are closely related to the stage of development that a cluster is experiencin g. For example, an emerging cluster is not actually a cluster, since the small number of firms is not expected to present a high level of linkages and do not form a critical mass. Moreover, the absence of strong interdependencies such as labour mobility, spin-off, socioeconomic networks and intense exchange of good and services prevent the emergence of local capabilities. Thus, same considering that this stage constitutes the embryo that determines the future cluster orientation, at this point the firms are not expected to be strongly influenced by a complex local dynamics.Observing that fact, Menzel and Fornahl (2010) present a skeptical position regarding the effectiveness of any competitiveness policy intended to stimulate the development of clusters at initial stages (agglomeration and emerging), since the existence of horizontal and vertical links among firms concentrated in the same region constitutes a very common fact around the world. Thus, it is almost impossible to distin guish agglomerations with real potential to become a cluster from less complex structures. Consequently, emerging clusters are almost always only described ex-post.After the initial stages of the clusters life cycle it is expected the development and intensification of interdependencies between firms within cluster boundaries (Press, 2006). Indeed the development of those interdependencies, firms start to resemble more with each other, being observe the emergence of convergent designs in terms of technological models (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010), specialized labour market (Cooke et al., 2007), production systems (Pitelis, 2010) and inter-firm relationships (Blien and Maier, 2008). Moreover, developing clusters also attract a high number of start-ups that act stimulating the intensification of intra-cluster relationships. This way, that process of convergence and expansion of the number of firms within the cluster boundaries culminates in the development of self-reinforcing external ec onomies that decrease the heterogeneity among firms at the same time that creates benefits like transactions cost economies and the privileged access to local knowledge.As clusters reach the stage of maturity, the standards and configurations originating from past decisions become consolidate and it is observed a reduction in the growth rate of firms attracted to the cluster (Klepper, 2007). At this point the cluster trajectory may take two different directions. Keep unchanged, and suffer with a homogenization process that creates bias economic activities and therefore prevent firms to adapt to external shocks (Menzel and Fornahl, 2010). That situation traps firms in previous successful development path and lead to the geographic dispersion of the local actors and to the deterioration of the interdependencies and capabilities. The other possible trajectory is observed in clusters that reach the stage of maturity and successfully sustain the local dynamics by a continuous process of reconfiguration and adaptation to the external shocks (Wolter, 2003).1.2 Clusters and Economic PerformanceThe extant theory offers a wide range of explanations to justify the economic and competitive benefits experienced by firms located within clusters. Krugman (1991) stress the existence of increasing returns originating from the concentration of firms in the same area, arguing that the geographic proximity puts together the main parts related to firms activities (e.g., labours, firms, suppliers and costumers) resulting in transaction costs economies. Following other perspective, Schmitz and Nadvi (1999) argue that unintentional external economies are not sufficient to explain the competitiveness of firms located within clusters, attributing to the existence of deliberate joint actions (e.g., sharing equipments, associations, strategic alliances and producers improving components) a critical source of the competitive advantages. Pitelis and Pseiridis (2006) explain the levels of c ompetitiveness and productivity associated with clustered firms considering the existence of specialized human resources, infrastructure and befits associated with unit costs economies complemented by the presence of an institutional atmosphere. Stressing a different point of view, Bahlmann and Huysman (2008) adopts the knowledge-based view of clusters to emphasize the relevance of knowledge spillovers among the firms to explain the advantages originated from the agglomeration process. Dupuy and Torre (2006) explains the existence of cluster in terms of the advantages originating from trust relationships that increase confidence and reduce risk and uncertainty about the intra-cluster operations taking place among the firms. Moreover, Zyglidopoulos et al. (2003), describe the positive effects that the reputation of a cluster may exert on the internalization process of small and micro enterprises through the alleviation of strategic constraints associated with factors like qualified w ork force, financing and reduction of the firms legitimation expenses.Despite that wide range of arguments, the most traditional perspective found in the cluster literature has explained the competitive advantages of clusters in terms of productivity and innovation (Pitelis, 1998 Porter, 1998), suggesting that the special characteristics originated from the economic and geographic proximity have significant impact on those two factors. Supplementary, Enright (1998) considers that the characteristics present inside the clusters local environment result in pressures, incentives and capabilities that increase the firms competitiveness comparatively to dispersed competitors, explaining the clustering process in terms of geographically restricted characteristics.Moreover, Solvell et al. (2003) suggests that the competitive advantages emerging from regional clusters may be classified as static and dynamics. According to this perspective, while the agglomeration process triggered and susta ined intensively or exclusively by factors like natural resources, low cost labors and government subsidies offers a vulnerable (easy to be copied, substituted or simple eroded by environmental changes) competitive position, clusters based on dynamics characteristics like multi-sectorial externalities, advantages of scale and scope and specific knowledge spillovers are more dynamics and competitive. Extending the arguments presented by Solvell and his colleagues, Andersson et al. (2004) considers that the sustainability of static and dynamic competitive advantages is not strictly determined, arguing that static factors are the main responsible for the emergence of clusters, while the dynamics factors are only developed along the different stages of the cluster life cycle.Complementing the understanding about the influence of the cluster dynamics on the firms economic performance some authors like Porter (2001) Garnsey and Heffernan (2007) Karlsson (2008) and Mason (2008) describe th e existence of a self-reinforcing process originating from the agglomeration externalities that contribute to create a regional virtuous-circle of increasing productivity, competitiveness and value creation. Following that argument, the economic and geographic proximity will stimulate firms to innovate more indeed benefits originating from local capabilities, which will stimulate even more the agglomeration process through the intensification of inter-firm relationships and the attraction of other firms from outside the cluster, which in turn will strength the local capabilities (Blandy, 2003, p. 101). Thus, the dynamics of clusters is expected to be self-reinforced by agglomeration benefits with significant influence on the firms performance.Putting together the arguments associated with the economic impacts experienced by clustered firms indeed the existence of local factors, it is possible to identify and describe the following positive location-specific externalitiesCost savings indeed the geographic proximity with specialized suppliers, labours and distributorsKnowledge-spillovers (intentional and unintentional), since firms inside clusters can benefit from the knowledge dissemination process that may take place especially through inter-firm cooperation, specific linkages and labour mobilityDeliberate joint actions facilitated by the engagement in alliances and partnerships to achieve strategic objectivesTrust relationships, that through the geographic and economic proximity minimize the uncertainty associated with commercial operations, resulting in transactions costs economiesPressures for higher performance, stimulated by the proximity with competitorsSpecific Infrastructure and public goods that are oriented to attend the cluster demands, like roads, ports, laboratories and telecommunication networksComplementarities, associated with firms in different activities but sharing common factors like raw material, clients and technologies that may enhance t he cluster efficiency as whole.Discussing the role of regional clusters in shaping competitive patterns, Tallman et al. (2004) proposes a distinction between the types of competitive advantages emerging from clustered firms based on traded interdependencies and based on untraded interdependencies. The concept of traded interdependencies is related to the existence of inter-firm transactions inside the cluster, and is observed in formal exchange operations that may take place in form of alliances, commercial operations and acquisitions. On the other hand, untraded interdependencies are related to less tangible effects, and are based on shared knowledge for which no market mechanism exists with no formal exchange of value for value (Tallman et al. 2004, p. 261). To illustrate the mechanisms by which the untraded interdependencies take place, it is possible to mention unintentional external economies associated with tacit knowledge shared through mechanisms like labor mobility.Those di fferent types of interdependencies, especially untraded, present at the cluster level, represent a source of competitive advantage that is likely to be causal ambiguous (for firms inside and outside the cluster) and high complex in terms of their origins, what consequently constitutes attributes difficult to be replicated by competitors. However, the presence of untraded effects, especially unintentional knowledge spillovers, is viewed Enright (1998) as a constraining factor for firms within clusters, since the establishment of an efficient information flow may limit the firms capacity to obtain monopoly profits from the development of innovations.Complementing the negative effects originating from the clusters dynamics, some authors also describe agglomeration diseconomies that have a negative impact firms located within clusters. For example, congestion effects (Arthur, 1990), institutional sclerosis (Pouder and John, 1996 Pitelis, 2010), rigidities associated with labour mobility and natural resources (Krugman, 1989) and pollution (Fan and Scott, 2003). This way, the dynamics and performance of a cluster is determined by the interplay between positive and negative externalities observed during the different stages of development that a cluster is expected to pass overtime (Wolter, 2003)Limitations in the Cluster TheoryNotwithstanding the advances in the cluster theory some questions still remain insufficiently explored. One of the main limitations observed in the current state of the cluster literature is the lack of comparative perspectives to explain the advantages and disadvantages of clusters relatively to other alternative models of organization of economic activities. In his very novel approach, Pitelis (2010) suggests that any perspective trying to explain clusters in terms of absolute advantages is at the very best incomplete. In this context, Pitelis proposes the comparison of clusters vis--vis to markets and hierarchies in order to understand the reasons and conditions that lead firms to engage in intra-clusters relationships, market operations (outside the cluster) or integrate within the firms hierarchy. In fact it is not necessary a great effort to conclude that most of the cluster theory has been developed following a mono-institutional approach (e.g. Porter, 1990, 1998 Saxenian, 1994 Rosenfeld, 1998 Swann and Sennett, 1998 Schmitz and Nadvi, 1999), while some few exceptions concentrated on transactions costs (e.g. Fujita and Thisse, 1996 Iammarino and McCann, 2006 Takeda et al., 2008) and knowledge creation efficiency (e.g. Hendry et al., 2000 Tracey and Clark, 2003 Reinau, 2007 Kongmanila and Takahashi, 2009) have been drawn on a comparative approaches between clusters and open-market operations. Assuming the arguments proposed by many scholars that clusters are engines of innovation (Davis, 2006, p. 32), the lack of comparative perspectives do not answer the question why clusters are more efficient than markets or the hierarchy to improve the firms innovative capacity (Pitelis, 2010). Thus, despite the wide number of ramifications observed in the cluster theory such as innovative efficiency, productivity, social capital and social interactions, its explicative power remains almost always restricted
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment